Article of the Month -
March 2004
|
Locating the “Country” in Town and Country Planning: the
Urban Bias in English Planning
Joel Bailey, Amanda Lewis and Frances Plimmer, United Kingdom
This paper has been
produced with the financial support of the FIG Foundation.
This article in PDF-format.
SUMMARY
This paper documents the development of English planning legislation and
the fallacy that reliance on agriculture would successfully replace
proactive planning policies in rural England. It discusses the effect of
affluent urban tourists and migrants into rural locations, seeking to
perpetuate the traditional perception of the rural idyll, without
recognising the intrinsic needs of those who rely on local-based employment
and development.
The paper argues that planning as a formal practice of government in
England has perpetuated an urban bias and a prejudice against the
socio-economic needs of the rural population. Prejudice and bias is
exhibited through the goals of planners, the policies they create, and the
modes of operation and implementation they undertake. Yet, although these
elements provide useful reference points from which to trace an urban bias
in planning, this paper delves deeper, to the root causes of urban bias, and
its evolution from attitudinal and cultural prejudices, to form structural
frameworks which, in ignorance of the economic and physical developmental
needs of the countryside population, perpetuate the original cultural and
attitudinal prejudices.
1. INTRODUCTION
“Planning is constantly seeking to assess the merits
of development against the demands of conservation. However, in making
such assessments it is not neutral: it has its own goals, policies and
modes of operation.” (Murdoch & Abram 2002, p.3)
The currency and necessity of this debate cannot be denied.
House-building in England has fallen to historic lows, with reports of a
”yawning gap” between supply and demand, especially in the south east of
England (Joseph Rowntree Foundation, 2002). This has led to rising pressure
on house prices, so that “in 46 of the 87 unitary councils outside London an
income of more than £30,000 is required to buy a home with a 95% mortgage,”
(Weaver 2002) a figure that is out of reach to those on an “average”
household income of £24,960. What is becoming increasingly clear is that
more housing is needed. However, it is the location of the house-building
that is at issue. When the Royal Town Planning Institute proposed, in 2002,
a review of green belt policy (that peri-urban region which divides the
urban from the rural), its proposal for a more proactive, modernised and
less crude form of urban management was met with vociferous and polemical
opposition.
This is only one example of many factors contributing to the growing
”rural question”. Add to it the recent bout of food scares, such as BSE and
Foot & Mouth Disease, and it appears that British rural areas are in a state
of urgent crisis. However, it is important to note that this sense of
urgency is in reaction to relatively recent threats against urbanism, and to
the UK urban economy - in the shape of an overheated housing market and
threats to consumer health - and not direct threats to the rural economy.
Although currently presented as a rural crisis by the media, the rural
economy has in fact been gradually eroded by fifty-five years of dogmatic
adherence to protectionist, centrist and agricultural fundamentalist
ideologies. Through an improved understanding of how urban bias exists and
operates, both structurally and attitudinally, in UK planning, this paper
seeks to explain the core reasons why rural problems have gone unchecked for
so long.
1.1 The Theoretical Context of “Urban Bias”
The theory of urban bias is not a new one, however its application within
the context of British planning is limited. The post-war Annales school of
French historiography noted that “an unconscious urban bias has been one of
the persistent defects of both liberalism and Marxism”. (Goldfrank 2000
p.162) A number of theorists have since taken the urban bias theory forward,
in an effort to understand better the complex interrelations that exist
between urban and rural populations and their economic activity.
Urban bias theory was first applied in this way in relation to developing
countries by Lipton in 1977, who deduced that vulnerability to famine was
often due to biased government policies, which favoured urban elites and
consequently discriminated against those living in rural areas.
“The rural sector contains most of the poverty, and most of the
low-cost sources of potential advance; but the urban sector contains most of
the articulateness, organisation and power. So the urban classes have been
able to ”win” most of the rounds of struggle with the countryside.” (ibid.,
p.13)
Lipton (ibid.) identified how a structural imbalance of power, away from
peripheral, predominantly rural areas, towards urban political and
commercial centres led to an explicit imbalance in resource allocation, and
drove an implicit deficit in the field of policy making.
“Many governments have . . . tended to look at rural and urban
development as separate issues rather than as closely related issues.” (UN
Economic & Social Council 2001, p.2)
Another theorist, Chambers (1983, 1993, 1997), developed the theory of
urban bias in a second, tangential, but related route. His findings reveal
that, prior to becoming structural, the root of much urban bias was
primarily attitudinal, and influenced by the cultural background and
experience of the individual. In his view, policy-makers, academic
researchers, economic and political representatives are overwhelmingly
educated within urban-based educational establishments, where “prolonged
professional conditioning has built biases of perception deep into many of
those concerned with rural development.” (Chambers 1983, p.6) These
professionals also operate within a marketplace in which they are inclined
to “respond to the pulls of central location, convenience, opportunities for
promotion, money and power,” (ibid., p.171) all of which imply urban
employment. This leads to a situation where theoretical frameworks are
established in and for urban areas, many of which are alien to and
discordant with rural contexts.
As Lassey remarks of rural planning in North America:
“The rural regions have not (at least until very recently) been
overtly recognised as having distinctively different characteristics and
planning requirements. The consequence of this urban bias has been a serious
neglect of professional preparation for planning in rural regions.” (Lassey
1977, p.9)
In analysing the structural and attitudinal components of urban bias in
UK planning, this paper therefore expands on the work of these early
studies.
2. CONTEXT OF A STRUCTURAL URBAN BIAS - THE LEGACY OF 1947
2.1 The Urban Image of “Rural”
“From ancient times to the present day, attitudes to the countryside have
been shaped by a response which we can term the pastoral.” (Short 1991,
p.8). This tendency to colour rural areas with near mythological features of
”goodness” and ”virtue” is especially prevalent in England.
“The contrasting image of the evil city dominated by the love of
money, a moral cesspit [is] to be contrasted with the fresh air, moral
purity and good life of the country... The myth has increased in potency as
urbanization and modernization have continued apace.” (ibid., p.31)
British planning has its roots in the late-nineteenth century, yet it
formally emerged in the mid twentieth century, following on closely from two
world wars - a period of enormous social upheaval in the UK. Throughout the
conflict, rurality became “the scene of national harmony, peace and
stability, to be contrasted with the conflict, strife and change of the
present; it [became] the container of national identity and the measure of
social change.” (ibid., p.34). However:
“. . . the tendency of the English to idealize rural life is not new. It
is connected with a literary tradition of pastoral poetry and art that has
an almost uninterrupted history of over two thousand years in Western
European culture. It is rooted in the Arcadian ideal of the identity between
nature and civilisation, but its precondition is, above all, a latent
conflict between town and country”. (Newby 1979, p.15)
It was perhaps inevitable then that when the revered rural became
challenged by unrestrained urban growth the impulsive reaction would be to
restrict urbanism and protect rural areas.
Centrism, urban containment and rural protectionism have therefore a long
heritage within the English psyche. Although these concepts were once deemed
supportive of rural well-being, and institutionalised as such, they have
since proved economically and socially destructive, and prejudicing against
the potentially beneficent aspects of development and decentrism. Newby
(1979, p. 19) notes how the strongest adherents of protectionist concepts,
”the English middle class”, has concentrated “on rural aesthetics rather
than rural economics”. Meades (2002, p. 1) provides a similar perspective:
“The supreme importance of the picturesque is a national bane. It has us
all in its thrall. It militates against an understanding of the rurality.”
This overwhelming concern with rural aesthetics and ignorance of rural
economics is central to urban bias, which prejudices rural policy to the
aspirations of an urban class.
As a result, for the past fifty-five years, the countryside has been
protected “for its own sake” (DoE 1998), “because it defined and reflected
Englishness” (Murdoch 1996, p.141), even when evidence has been mounting
that protectionist and conservationist policies are contributing to the
stagnation of an increasingly destabilised rural economy. An investigation
revealed that:
“. . . nine in ten people agree that society has a moral duty to
protect the countryside for the future and the same number agree that the
countryside should be protected at all costs. . . . people benefit from
”just knowing it is there”, even if they have little or no physical contact
with the countryside.” (Countryside Agency 1997, p.3)
The danger is that the ambitions of urban voters for a preserved
landscape, which is generally experienced in a superficial, visual manner,
displaces the deeper socio-economic requirements made of the land by the
resident rural population. (Cullingworth & Nadin 2002, p.273) As Lubbock
puts it:
“The countryside is sacrosanct: Nature has become our God, ecology our
religion, and a new theocracy of platonic guardians is stealthily preparing
to take over political control from our imperfect democratic institutions by
scaring us with an environmental doomsday.” (Lubbock 2002, p.3)
Hewison portrays:
“a country obsessed with its past and unable to face its future...
Hypnotised by images of the past, we risk losing all the capacity for
creative change.” (Hewison, 1987, p.43)
In many ways, it is these “ideological hang-ups which will end up doing
us grievous economic and social harm” (Hall, 2002), and preclude more
pragmatic approaches to the management of land resources in the UK. However,
the original framework of the current Town and Country Planning system,
based almost entirely on the unquestioning belief in the benefits of rural
protectionism and the primacy of agricultural fundamentalism, continues to
persist.
2.2 Moves towards Planning
Planning was established as a reaction to the industrial processes
associated with urbanism - increased migration, escalating urban populations
and rationalised production (Rydin 1993). New centripetal forces were
driving unprecedented growth of urban areas, which were in turn challenging
the classical connotations of English ruralism. Some form of management was
needed to resolve the ideological challenges that urbanism posed on the
ingrained rural ideal. As a result, the rise of planning became concordant
with the rise of urbanism.
Urbanism was generally thought to be unnatural and antithetical to the
”goodness” of ruralism, partly because planning at government level
developed from radical public health and housing policies. For example, the
1845 Royal Commission on the State of Large Towns equated urbanism with
disease and danger, and prescribed large-scale demolition of slums, and the
subsequent displacement of large numbers of people. The question as to where
these people were to be housed informed the new theories of urban
management, distinguished by the Garden City work of Ebenezer Howard. From
the early days of planning, a great emphasis was therefore placed “on
raising the standards of new development.” (Cullingworth & Nadin 2002, p.15)
However, the principle of planning legislation was not simply driven by
the need for improved built environments. Secondary, but no less
importantly, was the axiom that the countryside must be preserved from urban
encroachment. There were three separate strands to this principle: the
preservation of rural land for urban amenity; the preservation of ”rural
character” on behalf of the rural community; and the protection of rural
agricultural production for the benefit of the whole nation.
“By the late 19th Century,. . . public concern with the countryside
was evidenced in the number of societies formed around these issues.” (Rydin
1993, p.21)
These include the Commons, Footpaths and Open Space Society of 1865, the
1889 Royal Society for the Protection of Birds, and the National Trust for
Places of Historic Interest or Natural Beauty of 1895.
Just as these organisations continue to garner their membership from the
burgeoning middle-class, so they originally espoused urban middle-class
aspirations and fears. Their fundamental concern was with an audio-visual,
picturesque rural experience; open fields to look at, birds to listen to,
buildings to visit. Concerns over possible threats to the rural economy were
notably absent. Rural amenity, experienced audio-visually, was deemed a
healthy antidote to the alienating urban experience, and, in a precursor to
formal green belt policy, meant that proximate rural areas adjoining towns
and cities should be preserved for the benefit of urbanites.
Another driver for a preserved rural ”character”, was again orchestrated
largely by urban interests. According to Hall et al., (1973 p. 49)
“Patrick Abercrombie and a few others set up the Council for the
Preservation of Rural England [CPRE] in 1925... [they] immediately began to
wage a ceaseless war, under Abercrombie’s chairmanship, against the invasion
of the countryside by speculative building, and quickly built up a position
as a force to be respected.”
Once again, the war against the city was not being fought on
socio-economic grounds, by rural inhabitants themselves, but by self-elected
urban representatives “primarily concerned to protect the countryside on
more explicitly aesthetic grounds.” (Murdoch 1996, p.141). In a neat
articulation of middle class idealisation of the British countryside, which
the CPRE continues to pursue: “the town should indeed be frankly artificial,
urban; the country natural, rural.” (Abercrombie quoted ibid., p.141)
It was assumed that agriculture was somehow symbiotic with ruralism, and
that it would, by its very nature, continue to provide the essential
pastoral service of land husbandry, while also physically limiting urban
growth and providing a central core for the rural economy. This assumption
was backed up by a powerful farming lobby, a “. . . dominant force in the
coalition for urban planning controls.” (ibid., p.19)
This “unholy alliance” between farmers and the middle class invoked the
“fateful fallacy . . . that the ”traditional rural way of life” was
beneficial to all rural inhabitants.” (Newby 1979, p.239) As a result, the
improvement of agriculture as the sole raison d’etre of the
countryside” (Cherry and Rogers 1996, p.199) informed the architects of the
Town and Country Planning Act five years later, and
“. . . in a classic example of regulatory capture, agricultural uses
such as farm buildings, fences and hedgerow grubbing were exempt from the
planning permissions which were standard for other developments.”
(Pennington 1996, p.19)
2.3 The Legacy of the 1947 Legislation
This assumptiveness of the 1947 legislation has contributed to a number
of lasting legacies. Primarily, it revealed a lack of understanding and
degree of shortsightedness concerning rural needs that was to become
characteristic of rural planning. By 1947, agricultural intensification and
industrialisation was already evident, yet it was assumed that the sector
was immune to the full extent of modernisation and industrialisation
advancing through every other sector. For example, the single dissenting,
yet ignored, voice of the 1942 Scott Committee, the economist Professor S R
Dennison, argued “that a prosperous agriculture did not necessarily mean a
large traditional agriculture.” (Hall et al. 1973, p.51) In fact, as Newby
(1979, p. 239) states:
“. . . the rural poor had little to gain from the crucial committees
which evolved the planning system from the late 1940s onwards. Consequently
the 1947 Act framed the objectives of rural planning in terms of the
protection of an inherently changeless countryside and a consensual ”rural
way of life” that overlooked important social differences within the rural
population.”
Thereby the reality of change, and a flexibility to cater for it, was
denied from the outset.
One of the greatest failures of the legislation was that it provided no
contingency should “the disastrous consequences of a subsidised, mechanised
agriculture” become a reality. (Pennington 1996, p.20) Instead it
established a self-perpetuating conceptual framework and rationale that has
proved inflexible in its adherence to protectionism and centrism through
agricultural primacy. Even as agriculture has rescinded its central role in
many rural areas, leaving a vacuum at the heart of rural planning, the
framework has proved both unable and unwilling to respond with proactive
measures to fill the void.
The chief legacy of 1947 is therefore that rural planning has become “. .
. primarily about containing the spread of the urban, in order to maintain a
national treasure (the countryside for the preservationists) and a national
resource (agricultural land for food production)” (Cherry and Rogers 1996,
p.198). Thus,
“protection of the countryside has . . . been institutionalised and
become part of the rationale of the State.” (Murdoch 1996, p.142)
Furthermore, by establishing agricultural primacy, the architects of the
1947 legislation effectively abdicated planning responsibility for more than
50% of the UK land mass. Thereafter planners would be precluded from the
direct management of rural areas, and instead find their focus irrevocably
trained on urban issues. The removal of this ”white land” from the
development landscape also led to the creation of a perpetual, artificial
land crisis, “a figment of the imagination”, (Lubbock 2001, p.3) that “we
must save land” (Hall, 2001, p.101) which continues to distort effective
land-use thinking to this day. (Newby 1979)
Twenty four years have passed since Newby wrote these words, and rural
issues have become ever more complicated, yet the ageing framework of rural
planning has remained as crude and unresponsive as ever. As the following
section illustrates, the reason that the planning system has failed to
respond is that it is fundamentally prejudiced against rural needs.
2.4 The Divorce of Agriculture from the Rural Economy
Prior to the globalisation of markets, agricultural self-sufficiency was
a central component to any self-respecting national policy. (Buckwell 1997).
Not only would a prioritised agriculture produce the raw materials to
feed the population, but it would also provide essential material for
industrial production and manufacturing. Thus, the Agriculture Act of 1947
could readily commit to a: “. . . stable and efficient [agricultural]
industry capable of producing such part of the nation’s food and other
agricultural produce as in the national interest it is desirable to produce
in the United Kingdom.” (Allanson & Whitby 1996, p.3)
However, agriculture had an implicit secondary role - it formed the
organic core of the rural economy. Agriculture has always exhibited
“important multiplier effects on the total level of economic activity within
the local economy” (Hodge 1997, p.192), especially through employment,
which, prior to the twentieth century, accounted for 21.4% of workforce
employment. Thereafter, numbers in agricultural employment have fallen
steadily, with the 1991 census revealing a meagre 1.8% share. (Allanson &
Whitby 1996) A combination of “farm rationalisation, mechanisation,
intensification and specialisation” meant that new techniques could provide
for larger economies of scale, at the expense of human resources. (ibid.,
p.5) As agricultural employment fell, agricultural activity became
increasingly decoupled from the rural economy. Also, agricultural produce
was no longer bound by spatially constricted markets, but instead became
available within a global marketplace. (Hodge 1997)
Agriculture has gradually re-orientated its focus to centralised, and by
implication, urbanised markets, and the profits emerging from those
commercial centres are rarely reinvested in rural areas through employment.
As a result, agriculture has become increasingly directed by urban interests
at the same time as it has become further detached from the interests of the
rural economy.
This decoupling of agriculture from traditional agrarianism is compounded
by mounting evidence of farming’s environmentally detrimental impacts.
Economic rationalisation has replaced the mythical smallholder, the ”husband
of the land” farmer, with environmentally scarring ”agri-businesses”,
utilising intensive and mechanised processes (Robinson 1990). Between 1945
and 1970, changes in agricultural activity have led to the removal of one
percent, or 8,000 km. of hedgerows annually, and the cumulative destruction
of 80% of chalk grassland, 60% of heathland and 50% of wetlands (Pennington
1996). The result has been the creation of an “arable desert” of
catastrophic proportions, singularly lacking in the biodiversity so
cherished in mythologised images of rurality. (ibid.) Gradually, “people
have got wise” to the dangers inherent in agricultural primacy and
systematic subsidy, but “there’s still this notion that farmers are the
stewards of the land.” (Hall 2002)
Although the divorce of agriculture from its traditional seat at the
centre of the rural economy has driven a number of rural inhabitants into
urban-based work, relative rural population numbers have not dropped, with
many simply choosing to accommodate changing occupational opportunities and
staying on to find new work. (Allanson & Whitby 1996) Planning policy has
failed to provide for these individuals and the changing economic demands
being placed upon them. “By effectively constraining the extent of
non-agricultural development in rural areas” planning policy has offered
“limited alternative employment opportunities for the rural working.”
(ibid., p.5) A loosening of blanket rural protection policies has not
occurred, and the rural working class continue to be denied economic
opportunity.
The overall picture is therefore one in which agriculture is distanced
from the rural economy, becoming more a consumer (and even destroyer) of
rural resources, rather than a producer of them. Corporate agribusinesses no
longer have a vested interest in the rural economy, but are instead directed
by urban interests. (Newby 1979) Farmers have not acted alone in this
gradual reorientation of rural areas to urban interests. Pennington notes
that the administration of agricultural subsidy has necessitated a
burgeoning government bureaucracy, which perpetuates the existence of
agricultural primacy within planning. It is claimed that these bureaucrats,
based in Ministry of Agriculture Forestry and Fisheries (MAFF) offices in
Whitehall, have vested
“. . . budgetary interests . . . firmly linked to the expansion of the
subsidised sector. If more land was taken for non-agricultural development,
the power of the farmers and the size of the agricultural budget would
decrease and thus the discretionary grant-giving of MAFF bureaucrats.”
(Pennington 1996, p.19)
Such was their concern for continued subsidy that, in 1984, MAFF
undertook direct administration of any local authority planning application
that proposed removing more than two hectares of land from agriculture.
(ibid.)
The activities of the farm lobby and MAFF bureaucrats echo components of
Lipton’s structural bias (Lipton 1977). Agricultural interests, now largely
dislocated from the rural economy, articulate their influence through
centralised, urban mechanisms of government, such as planning, that
effectively marginalise the needs of the rural economy and environment.
However, shifts in the rural-agrarian power base provides for only half the
story: “the power of the urban elite . . . is determined, not by its
economic power alone, but by its capacity to organise, centralise and
control.” (Lipton 1982, p.66). However agriculture provides only one
dimension to the problem. This leads into a second field of study, of
perhaps even greater significance - the urbanisation of rural space.
3. “URBS IN RURE” - THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC URBANISATION OF RURAL SPACE
Pahl, in 1964, was amongst the first to bear witness to the enormous
upheaval of traditional ways of life. His analysis of the migration of ”urbs
to rure” revealed how migration of urban classes into rural communities was
blurring the sacrosanct distinction between ”town” and ”country”. (Pahl,
1970)
Over three decades later and rural commentators were still tracing the
change: “As has been the case for over a century, rural England (in
particular) is being colonized by urban interests”. (Cherry & Rogers 1996,
p.195)
The counter-urbanisation trends of the late twentieth-century have
rendered the ”urbs in rure” an increasingly commonplace occurrence. Whereas
much of the formative 1947 ideology was articulated by middle-class urban
interests looking outward from the city, upon their cherished rural
amenities, those urban interests have now found the means to both access and
accommodate rural areas. This has fundamentally altered the fault-lines of
power, away from Lipton’s simplified model of centre and periphery, towards
one that is more disparate, dislocated and diffuse, yet no less influential.
Increased access to rural areas, by way of temporary visits and complete
migration, has been concomitant with an urbanisation of rural policy. In an
extension of the nineteenth century public amenity debate, rural areas are
increasingly identified as public amenity, a ”common” and ”shared” resource,
with implied rights to roam. The influential 1947 Hobhouse Report “argued
for a public right of access to all open countryside . . . freedom to ramble
across the wilder parts of the country.” (Cullingworth & Nadin 2002, p.273)
This campaign for public access is now an unquestioned component of rural
policy. Rightly or wrongly, this idyllic view of the countryside, marked as
it is by the audio-visual experience of the tourist, is characteristic of
the ascendant, popular assumption that, in place of reduced agricultural
use, rural areas are there to serve the recreational and tourist needs of a
prevailing urban population (ibid.). Although tourism has overtaken
agriculture as the largest employer in many rural areas, providing for an
essential economic boost, other non-agricultural uses, arguably of more
sustainable value, have been largely excluded from debate.
However, beyond the influence of urban tourism on rural planning policy,
perhaps the greatest articulation of urban interest is taking place from
within rural areas. Counter-urbanisation trends have been recognised for
many years. Between 1991 and 1997, 122 rural areas made a net gain of
540,000 people, an average of 90,000 people per year. (Countryside Agency
1999, p.10). Furthermore, the greatest migration losses both for 1981-91 and
also 1991-95 were from Greater London and the six metropolitan counties
(ibid., p.11) This evidence provides the latest illustration of the
long-running move of ”urbs to rure”, and the introduction of a polar ”class”
division (with its undertones of conflict) on a local social status
hierarchy similar to that first witnessed by Pahl in 1964.
These incomers - retirees, commuters and second-home owners - tend to
arrive with an embedded urban awareness of rurality, that finds comfort in
the pastoral vision of a ”slower” and more ”tranquil” environment. In
effect, rural areas are expected to provide an experience that is
antithetical to the urban one left behind, even though similar urban
pressures play an increasingly important role across urban and rural regions
alike. As a result, the incomers are inevitably predisposed to the
protection and preservation of the rural environment, in which they have
invested their aspirations and their savings.
Furthermore, the economic role of these in-migrants is rarely one of
integration. Few take on directly productive functions, and even fewer
“support local service provision or employment opportunities.” (Hodge 1997,
p.197). Incomers tend to “ . . . have their own private transport and retain
strong social and economic links with a wider, urban society” and thus fail
to provide any significant economic role other than consumption. (ibid.,
p.198)
“An in-migration of people on relatively high incomes raises the
average standard of living but does not necessarily improve the lot of those
living on low incomes. Indeed there are grounds for believing that at least
in some circumstances and ways the position of the worst off may actually be
worsened. In-migration tends to stimulate higher house prices and so access
to the housing market becomes more difficult for those on a given income
level.” (ibid., p.197)
The result is that “the ”rural disadvantaged” become trapped within a
world of mobility and affluence, as local economic, infrastructure and
administrative networks are restructured around the needs of the mobile and
affluent.” (Cabinet Office 1999, p.23) However, this process does not occur
passively. On the contrary:
“the counterurbanisation trends and the invasion of the countryside by
the service class have inevitably impacted upon local government. The
dominance of farmers and landowners on local councils has undoubtedly been
waning since the middle of the 1960s as newcomers have moved to rural areas
and have been elected at all levels of local government.” (Cherry & Rogers
1996, p.173)
Through these positions, politically active middle class newcomers can
exercise a “moratorium on most types of development except those that fit in
with the local ”aesthetic”. Preservationism will rule.” (Murdoch 1996,
p.145)
Although once the traditional locus of rural power in the UK, farming can
no longer claim to be the dominant interest group. Instead its position has
been usurped by conservation groups such as the Council for the Protection
of Rural England (CPRE) and Friends of the Earth. (Pennington 1996)
The influence of these groups, and the individuals they represent, has
become so pervasive as to warrant new monikers: NIMBY (”Not In My BackYard”)
and BANANA (”Build Absolutely Nothing Anywhere Near Anybody”). Both have
evolved as appropriate definitions for an urban class that seeks to preserve
rural areas, “not in aspic but in vinegar.” (Monbiot 2002, p13) Hall (2002)
summed up the situation thus:
“Most of the people involved [with nimbyism] are ex-urbanites and
often quite recent arrivals in the countryside. They have relatively little
interest in the rural economy. The people who are losing out are the lower
income rural people, whose children can no longer afford housing. That’s the
tragedy in all this.”
This urban prejudice has been effectively articulated.
“Local preservation and protection societies, sometimes ad hoc in
their origins and operation, sometimes linked federally to national
groupings such as the Council for the Protection of Rural England, have been
ever-vigilant in safeguarding rural amenity and limiting development. Whilst
ostensibly those groups attempt to gain their ends by publicly representing
”local opinion”, it is clear also that they are often quite closely linked
with the formal planning process.” (Murdoch 1996, p.174)
To return to Lipton’s theories; in developing countries, the exploitation
of a rural class by an urban class was performed in a far more explicit
manner to the situation in the UK, where the process is more implicit, but
no less destructive. “”What is at issue is not so much domination and
subordination, as a capacity to act and accomplish goals”” (Stone as quoted
by Goodwin 1998, p.10). According to Stone, the gentrifying middle-class
migrant therefore exercises a form of social and economic ”power to”,
generated through ”social production,” rather than the traditional ”power
over,” characteristic “of landed elites and paternalistic gentry”. (ibid.)
Therefore, although diffuse across rural areas, an incoming ”urban class”
has exploited the planning system to its own protectionist needs, and thus
subordinated the interests of indigenous rural populations.
4. PLANNING FROM THE CENTRE - THE PERPETUATION OF URBAN PREJUDICE
In their study of European planning systems, Newman and Thornley outline
the numerous models used to describe:
“the relationship between central and local government, one of which
is the ”agency model” . . . In this model local authorities are seen as
agents carrying out central government policies and so central government
regulations, laws and controls are formulated to allow this to happen . . .
Britain is moving very close to this agency model. In the last decade the
autonomy of local government has been consistently eroded as central
government has increased its financial controls.” (Newman & Thornley 1996,
p.31)
Duncan and Goodwin (1988, p. 250) have termed this process, the
”nationalisation” of policy-making; “policy is decided at the centre and
regional and local offices exist only as administrative units.” They trace
this nationalisation process through the late seventies and early eighties,
when, “in the face of... continued political challenges the Government began
to tackle the ”representational” role of local councils (i.e. removing their
ability to represent local electorates effectively) as well as their
”interpretive” role (i.e. removing their influence on policy content).”
(ibid., p.169) As a result, most areas of government policy have lost their
localised dimensions. In terms of rural planning, this has had the dramatic
effect of divorcing policy-creation from the area to which policy will be
applied. Rural policy is created in the Department of Transport, Local
Government and the Regions (DTLR), MAFF and Department for Environment, Food
and Rural Affairs (DEFRA) offices in Whitehall, central London, for delivery
out into rural areas. There is little provision for constructive feedback,
and even less allowance for interpretive implementation.
This shift in government structure has effectively disenfranchised rural
areas from representing their own, often unique, localised needs, and from
applying their own solutions. “Instead, the ”democratic vacuum” has been
filled by those who do have a direct interest”, which, in the absence of
local representation, is defined through interest group politicking (ibid.,
p.254).
“New non-elected agencies were funded from the centre to provide
services previously delivered through local government… Some of these
quangos [Quasi Autonomous Non-Governmental Organisations] are appointed
directly by central government, others are self-governing in the sense that
they appoint their own boards... These and others like them are now
responsible for over £40 billion of public funds, a figure not far below the
sum spent in total by elected local authorities... the institutional map of
local government in this country has been transformed beyond recognition.”
(Goodwin 1998, p.7)
This post-Fordist shift from government through public body, to
governance through a combination of public and private efforts, introduces a
stark problem. Whereas local representation meant that local people had to
live with their political choices, the intervention of quangos has blurred
the boundary between private and public responsibility and accountability.
In effect, policy is now created by “bureaucrats and interest groups [who]
do not bear the full opportunity cost of their actions.” (Pennington 1996,
p.49)
Planning policy in the UK has therefore not only lost a crucial local,
and thus rural dimension, to central, urban government, but it has also seen
the democratic vacuum filled by unaccountable quangos, which do not bear the
opportunity costs of the decisions they impose ”top down” on rural areas.
Rural issues are therefore lost within the planning framework, with very few
coherent, ”bottom up” channels through which to reach policy-makers.
“Critical questions emerge over who has been involved in new forms of
governance and who hasn’t, and why this is the case.” (Goodwin 1998, p.10)
In terms of rural policy the new challenge of rural governance is to erase
the continued reliance on top-down, “vertical relations”, and “to shift the
inherited institutional structure . . . into a richer, more place-focused,
more future-oriented and more localised form.” (Vigar et al. 2000, p.289).
English planning, however, seems to be gravitating the other way.
This section has illustrated how influential institutions are the outcome
of a political system that provides undue representation to urban interests.
Yet it has also revealed how bleak the prospects for change are. The
planning system, dominated as it is by an ”Iron Triangle” of urban,
political and economic power, continues to validate protectionism and
centrism, and thus preclude proactive change.
“It is surely not premature to ask whether conservation, as at present
practised in the UK, is an effective instrument for protecting and enhancing
the visual environment, or whether it has become too introspective in its
objectives, too detached from other legitimate concerns of urban planning
and the needs of the countryside . . . It is difficult to think of any other
area of government activity where the system has remained substantially
unchanged for half a century, and where policy has remained essentially
immune to questioning, even when it has tended to doctrinaire extremes.”
(Delafons 1997, p.112)
But how can change occur when urban interests have such a grip on rural
policy?
5. TRACING ATTITUDINAL URBAN BIAS
“Historically... rural planning has been virtually a by-product of a
system designed to cope with urban growth, partly because the countryside
was regarded as a bucolic backdrop to life in urban areas and partly because
the idea of a planned countryside was, to influential public opinion,
anathema.” (Newby 1979, p.228)
When the Town and Country Planning Act was established in 1947, planners
effectively abdicated responsibility for rural areas to agriculture.
Ruralism did not require management in the way urbanism did, and thus
planning professionals have failed to develop a full understanding of
ruralism’s distinct requirements. But rural planning by default is no longer
viable.
“As the old agricultural order disappears, we have yet to specify
clearly the alternative structural objectives that define the types of rural
communities that are desired in its place.” (Hodge 1997, p.199)
It is becoming increasingly clear that planners must fundamentally
reappraise their long-standing neglect for rural areas, so that a greater
degree of socio-economic parity can be achieved. To support this shift, a
rural perspective is required at the level of individual planners.
“It is important to recognise that people live ”out there”... to
ignore them is a colonising attitude. I suspect that city officials and
their planners assume that the space outside the city limits is limitless.
There is space to expropriate, play in, fish from, build on, and provide a
convenient dump for garbage.” (Sim 1993, p.460)
Planners must recognise that “rural is not another country”. (Lock 2001,
p.47) The education, professional training, and overall culture of planning
practice in the UK has led to a perpetuation of urban bias within planning.
“It is true that countryside planning has probably been relatively
poorly taught in planning schools. Most of them don’t even have rural
experts. Even the Bartlett School of Planning, where I sometimes teach, has
no permanent rural expert, although we do get someone in... So yes, there
has been a failure, adequately to teach countryside planning in planning
schools...” (Hall 2002)
This remark provides critical evidence of the central failure of rural
planning; that the planning curriculum neglects the specificities and
uniqueness of rural areas.
“Britain’s planning system has had a built- in urban orientation...
[which] meant that what stood for rural planning was essentially negative,
its objectives being to prevent unwelcome forms of urban development in the
countryside.” (Cherry and Rogers 1996, p.192)
Implicit is the assumption that ruralism is the absence of activity; a
perpetual state of organic passivity. However, this paper has already
revealed how the line between ruralism and urbanism is increasingly blurred,
so that such assumptions can no longer stand. Unfortunately rural thinkers
and experts have not extended their field of vision to cater for this
change.
Anderson and Bell (2000) note how: “...in recent years most of the
various disciplines of rural studies have been strangely silent on economic
issues”. (ibid., p.269) Similarly, Goodwin remarks how “there has been an
increasingly noticeable silence at the centre of contemporary rural studies
concerning the ways in which rural areas are governed.” (Goodwin 1998, p.5)
Both comments point to a boundedness within academic thought that has
excluded a more dynamic sense of rural change, focusing on the secondary,
socio-cultural aspects of agricultural change, as opposed to primary
political and economic shifts where the contours of rural decay can be
readily seen.
“The concentration of policy-makers on agriculture in rural areas has
led to a neglect of broader and more integrated strategies and policies for
rural development - even though, given the shift of employment and output
away from primary industries, these broader strategies and policies are
necessary for effective government action in rural economies”. (Cabinet
Office 1999, p.54)
In a call for change, Anderson and Bell propose that:
“...consideration of the workings of the rural economy must lead rural
scholarship to take its focus off of the exclusively rural... We need work
that erases the heavy lines we have often scribbled in between the rural and
urban, the economic and the social, and the material and the cultural...
Difference exists. But we need to avoid the boundedness that comes from the
dichotomization of these differences.” (Anderson & Bell 2000, p.269-270)
Unfortunately, this drive towards a distinctive rural perspective is not
reflected by a concordant drive within the planning profession. A greater
“concern for the total fabric of the countryside” is still required
(Davidson and Wibberley 1977, p.167 & 169).
A key part of the battle for greater rural representation in planning is
improving the traditional, lowly status of rural work within the planning
profession. In researching this paper, numerous illustrations of prejudice
against rural planning were encountered, invariably characterising the rural
focus as the ”poor cousin” to urban work. This tendency is also reflected in
the literature.
“It has to be said… that relatively few chartered planners expressed much
interest in rural matters since urban problems were seen as more pressing.
Especially in the public sector, countryside planning was often viewed as at
best a tangential interest and at worst a professional backwater.” (Cherry
and Rogers 1996, p.205)
In many ways, this is a result of the natural centripetal trends
effecting society at large, to which Chambers refers when he notes that
development professionals “respond to the pulls of central location,
convenience, opportunities for promotion, money and power.” (Chambers 1983,
p.171) An article in the RICS Rural Professional magazine of January 2002,
provided graphic illustration of this trend in action:
“Intake at the Royal Agricultural College (RAC), the College of Estate
Management and other leading agricultural colleges has fallen significantly.
Allegedly, some 85% of RAC graduates have entered commercial property rather
than the rural environment.” (RICS 2002, p.17)
Young, career-minded professionals are becoming increasingly aware of
their market value and determining that rural work is less attractive than
urban. This is understandable when the average basic rural sector salary
begins at £26,310 against £33,077 in the commercial sector, with urban pay
scales increasing at rates far beyond those available to rural
professionals. (ibid., p.17)
Moreover, not only are professional planners being pulled towards urban
commercial work, which lacks any specific rural focus, but those who choose
to continue in rural practice find themselves increasingly based in the
urban locations from which governance is performed. In this way, policy is
created through an external understanding of rural areas, formulating rural
policy through a distorted, urban-oriented understanding of rural problems,
and tending towards Chambers’ model of the prejudiced “rural development
tourist”. (Chambers 1983, p.10)
The attraction to urbanism is not simply career-based but also aesthetic.
Over time, a majority of planners have subscribed to the urban vision
espoused by the urban designer and architect. Ever since ”Modernist
Planning” was taken up with near “animal unreason” in the 1920s, the appeal
of the grand urban solution has prevailed. (Hughes 1971, p.205 quoted by
Breheny 2000, p.18). The persistence of these ideas is clearly illustrated
by New Urbanist thought. As Hall notes, “there is nothing new about New
Urbanism” (Hall 2002b). “Richard Rogers used to be an ardent supporter of
modernist town planning - the old 1947 orthodoxy. Now he champions New
Urbanism... the New Orthodoxy... In fact, the overarching connection is
strong and is still almost identical to the Old Orthodoxy - the policy of
urban containment has if anything intensified.” (Lubbock 2001, p.3)
Although it is entirely sensible to maximise the use of urban space, and
to make cities as attractive as possible, what is at issue is a sense of
urban myopia within planning thought, which has led to the exclusion of
alternative, decentrist planning visions that could “allow for the
controlled direction of inevitable decentralisation... [taking] account of
the grain of the market, without being subservient to it.” (Breheny 2000,
p.32)
“It has to be said that [the Urban Renaissance] isn’t working. It’s
demonstrably plain because it’s delivering perhaps a third of the number of
houses we need - that ought to worry everyone.” (Hall 2002)
However, there has been no evidence of any contingency plans in the event
of New Urbanist failure. The problem of continuing migration out of the city
has been consistently ignored in favour of the big solution, the contained
and compact city, which has captured the attention of planners and
architects for the past 55 years. As a result, the impact of unmanaged
decentrism on rural areas continues unheeded.
6. CONCLUSION
This paper has traced the root causes and characteristics of a structural
and attitudinal urban bias within UK planning policy. The impacts of these
prejudices have proved destructive for rural areas, the interests of which
are largely misunderstood or under-represented within the planning system.
Yet this destructive tendency has also proved self-perpetuating, through
belief-systems that are sustained through both policy and practice. But the
disparity of this situation is not proceeding completely unheeded, and
recent events have given cause for some optimism. The British are committing
to early stages of positive reorientation.
However, it is in keeping with the core argument that these drives for
change have emerged, not on behalf of rural areas, but in reaction to
threats upon urban areas. In a final example of political cynicism and
endemic prejudice, it is significant that current planning policy has been
seriously challenged as a result of only twelve months of grievances
concerning threats to the urban economy (an overheating housing market, BSE
and Foot and Mouth food scares), when evidence of rural stagnation has gone
unheeded for the past thirty years.
Nevertheless, a key deliverable of the Rural White Paper, 2000, was a
Rural Proofing initiative, providing for a “systematic assessment of the
rural dimension of all government policies as they are developed and
implemented - nationally, regionally and locally.” (DETR 2000) In a direct
echo of Chamber’s antidote (Chambers 1983, p.168) to attitudinal bias,
“putting the last first” within the rural-urban relationship, Cameron, the
government’s newly appointed ”Rural Advocate”, has called upon policy-makers
to “think rural.” (Countryside Agency 2002, p.8)
“In the past, governments have not always been good at thinking about
how national policy might affect rural areas. The interests of those living
and working in rural areas have been occasionally overlooked or given lower
priority than urban interests. Policy makers did not always appreciate that
what works in urban areas will not automatically work in the countryside. As
a result, some policies have been less effective in rural areas, have failed
to target rural needs or have even brought about unintended adverse
impacts.” (ibid., p.9)
So, the Countryside Agency proposes structural changes: “the setting of
specific rural targets, and the monitoring and evaluation of rural
outcomes”, so as to avoid the tendency to meet national targets “most easily
- and at least cost - by concentrating policy delivery on urban centres.”
(ibid., p.17)
Furthermore, the report earmarks the importance of attitudes: “often,
where rural proofing occurs, it has more to do with the existing level of
awareness of particular individuals or policy teams”; and later “rural
proofing and mainstreaming rural thinking within general policy making is,
therefore, crucial.” (ibid., p.14 & 23)
So far however, the process has been only relatively successful. In
considering twenty-five policy developments initiated by the DTLR, which
administer planning, the report concluded that, “there has not been
sufficient rural thinking” (ibid., p.49). Cameron concludes that, “on the
basis of action so far, rural proofing is unlikely to become widely used and
routine.” (ibid., p.12). Nevertheless, the report marks the beginning of a
potentially valuable process, at a time when rural issues, if at least
peri-urban, remain high on the public agenda.
Questions pertaining to current planning theory and practice are
surfacing, yet the prospects for more balanced policy is some way off.
Although ”top-down” structural initiatives such as Rural Proofing provide a
useful starting point, sustained change within planning can only come about
through ”bottom-up” changes: creating a more balanced planning curriculum,
developing a specific framework for rural needs, improving the pay of rural
practitioners, and providing planners with the forums needed to cultivate
more realistic public attitudes to the countryside.
Urban bias is not unique to the UK. The paper offers insights into the UK
experience in order to inform what should be an on-going global debate. Some
of the UK problems may not be common to other systems, which may suffer from
other issues. However, the fundamental principle remains: rural communities
have the same right as urban communities to ensure that they benefit from
the socio-economic development of their localities through the country’s
planning system. Only with the necessary fundamentals at work can planning
abandon its prejudices and go on to provide effective, innovative and
proactive responses to rural problems.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This paper has been produced with the financial support of the FIG
Foundation. The authors are very grateful to the FIG Foundation for their
support.
REFERENCES
Allanson P & Whitby M (Eds) (1996) - The Rural Economy and the British
Countryside Earthscan Publications Ltd, London.
Anderson, C D & Bell, M M (2000) The Social Economy of Rural Life: an
introduction. Journal of Rural Studies 16 pp. 269-272.
Breheny, M (2000) Centrists, Decentrists and Compromisers: views on the
future of urban form. in The Compact City: A sustainable urban form?
Jenks M Burgess R (eds) E & FN Spon London.
Buckwell A (1997) “Rural Europe: a policy overview” - Built
Environment 23:3 pp.170-183
Cabinet Office (1999) Rural Economies: a performance and innovation unit
report December, Cabinet Office Stationery Office Publications Centre
Chambers, R (1993) Challenging the Professions: Frontiers for Rural
Development. Intermediate Technology Publications, London
Chambers, R (1983) Rural Development: Putting the Last First
Longman Scientific and Technical, Harlow, Essex
Chambers, R (1997) Whose Reality Counts? Putting the Last First
Intermediate Technology Publications, London
Cherry E & Rogers A (1996) Rural Change and Planning: England and
Wales in the Twentieth Century - 1996, E & FN Spon, London.
Countryside Agency (1999a) Living in the Countryside: the needs and
aspirations of rural populations Countryside Agency Publications,
Wetherby
Countryside Agency (1999b) Migration Impacts in Rural England
Countryside Agency Publications, Northampton
Countryside Agency (2002b) Rural proofing in 2001/02: a report to
government Countryside Agency Publications, Wetherby
Countryside Commission (1997) Public attitudes to the countryside
Countryside Agency Publications, Wetherby
Cullingworth B & Nadin V (2002) Town and Country Planning in the UK
- Routledge, London.
Davidson, J & Webberley G (1977) Planning and the Rural Environment
Peregammon Press, Oxford.
Delafons, J (1997) Sustainable Conservation - Built Environment
Vol. 23 No.2 pp.111-119
Department of Environment (1998) “PPG7” DoE.
DETR (2000) “Rural White Paper” DETR, London
Duncan & Goodwin (1998) The Local State and Uneven Development
Polity Press, Cambridge
Goldfrank, W L (2000) “Paradigm Regained? The Rules of Wallerstein’s
World-System Method” - Journal of World Systems Research, Vol 1, No 2,
Summer/Fall, pp150-195
Goodwin M (1998) “The Governance of Rural Areas: some emerging research
issues and agendas” - Journal of Rural Studies, Vol 14 No.1, pp.5-12.
Hall, P (2001) Sustainable Cities or Town Cramming in Layard A, Dovoudi S
Batty S (eds) Planning for a Sustainable Future Spon Press. London.
Hall P (2002) Interview conducted by the author, 2pm Tuesday 25th June
20.
Hewison, R (1987) The Heritage Industry: Britain in a climate of
decline Methuen, London
Hodge, Ian (1997) The Integration of the Rural Economy Built
Environment, Vol 23 No 3 pp.193-200
Joseph Rowntree (2002) Press Release. 19 March.
Lassey, W A (1977) Planning in Rural Environments, McGraw-Hill
Book Co, New York
Lipton, N (1977) Why poor people stay poor. Urban bias in developing
countries Templesmith, London.
Lipton, M (1982) Why poor people stay poor in Harris, J (ed) Rural
Development Theories of Peasant Economy and Agrarian Change Hutchinson &
Co. (Publishers) Ltd. London.
Lock, D (2001) Rural is not another country. Town and Country Planning.
February p. 47.
Lubbock, J (2001) “Planning is the problem” -
www.opendemocracy.net
Lubbock, J (2002) Interview conducted by the author, 4pm Thursday 4th
July
Meades, J (2002) “Death of the Picturesque!”
www.opendemocracy.net
Monbiot G (2002) “Rich man’s castle” - The Guardian - May 7th pp.13
Murdoch J (1996) “The Planning of Rural Britain” in Allanson P & Whitby M
(Eds) - The Rural Economy and the British Countryside Earthscan
Publications Ltd, London
Murdoch J & Abram S (2002) Rationalities of Planning Ashgate
Publishing Company, London
Newby, Howard (1979) Green and Pleasant Land? Social Change in Rural
England Hutchinson & Co. (Publishers) Ltd, Middlesex
Newman P & Thornley A (1996) Urban Planning in Europe: International
Competition, National Systems & Planning Projects, Routledge, London
Pahl R E (1970) Urbs in Rure: the metropolitan fringe in Hertfordshire.
London School of Economics and Political Science, London
Pennington, M (1996) Conservation and the Countryside: By Quango or
Market? - Institute of Economic Affairs, London
Robinson, G M (1990) Conflict and Change in the Countryside,
Belhaven Press, London
Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors (2002) RICS Housing Market. The
Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors. London. March.
Rydin Y (1993) The British Planning System: an introduction
Macmillan, London
Short, John R (1991) Imagined Country: Environment, Culture and
Society Routledge, London
Sim A (1993) Planning: a rural perspective. University of Toronto
Quarterly Vol 62 No 4 pp.456-473.
UN Economic and Social Council (2001) Proceedings of the 59th Session,
19-25th April 2001 Bangkok -
http://esa.un.org/ffd/policydb/PolicyTexts/escap-2.pdf - accessed 23rd
April 2002
Vigar G, Healy P, Hull A., (2000) Planning, Governance and Spatial
Strategy in Britain an institutionalist approach. Macmillan. London.
Weaver M (2002) “Property boom is making homeownership a no-go area” -
The Guardian -
http://society.guardian.co.uk/keyworkers/story/0,1266,546846,00.html
accessed 13th June 2002
BIOGRAPHICAL NOTES
Joel Bailey, BA (Hons), MA is currently working as a Project
Manager in New Zealand and the United Kingdom. This work is based on Joel’s
MA thesis at Kingston University.
Amanda Lewis BA (Hons) DipArch MSc RIBA ILTM is Principal Lecturer
and Director of Postgraduate Studies at the School of Surveying and was
supervisor to the research.
Dr. Frances Plimmer, Dip Est Man, MPhil, PhD, FRICS, IRRV is
Senior Researcher at the School of Surveying.
CONTACTS
Dr. Frances Plimmer
Tai-An
St. Andrews Road
Dinas Powys
Vale of Glamorgan CF64 4HB
UNITED KINGDOM
Tel. + 44 29 2051 5448
Email: [email protected]
|